China Research

A discussion forum on emerging markets, mainly China – from a macro, micro, institutional and corporate angle.

China’s political leadership and the coronavirus – how to handle growth objectives and statistics?

February 10, 2020

Hur kommer Kinas ledare att tackla coranavirusets negativa tillväxteffekter?

Summary / Sammanfattning på svenska

Det skrivs för närvarande väldigt mycket om de negativa effekterna på Kinas ekonomi p g a coronaviruset. Detta trots att det saknas underlag till mer precisa beräkningar. Effekter från minus 0.5 upp till minus 1.5 procent av BNP nämns såväl för det första kvartalet med åtföljande normalisering som för helåret 2020 – trots den helt omöjliga förutsebarheten. Dock förbises en annan intressant fråga: Hur kommer Kinas politiska ledare att tackla den kommande BNP-statistiken med tanke på det så sent som i januari i år uppsatta BNP-tillväxtmålet för 2020 på “omkring 6 procent”?

—————————————-

Every day we can read about revised GDP forecasts on China as a consequence of the coronavirus. Economists “introduce” themselves as medical doctors, virologists and experts on both Chinese politics and statistics – many of these economists, however, dealing with China only occasionally. For this reason, readers of these new China forecasts should be very careful and also consider possible psychological overreactions or minimization. I hereby stress the word “possible”. An unknown factor is also Africa with many Chinese working there. Hopefully, negative news from there will not reach us.

Analysts neglect the political strategy conflicts

The coronavirus does not fit at all in the communist party’s economic planning process. First, there is – or should be according to previous plans – the “evaluation” of the 60 relatively detailed reform plans from the Third Plenum in 2013 which should give “significant” results by 2020.

Second, in 2021 the Communist Party of China will celebrate its 100 th anniversary. A major weakening of GDP-growth the year before would certainly not be appreciated by the leaders of the strong Standing Committee and all the other highly ranked party officers.

Third, the next five-year plan will start already in 2021. This means that the underlying growth trend will be even more difficult to find if the coronavirus really should cause structural or sustained psychological damage. And it is certainly not easy to recognize and determine appropriate assumptions and preconditions five years ahead in this critical and not normal year of 2020.

Fourth, considerably slower GDP growth in 2020 could indeed jeopardize the official objective to double GDP in the decade to 2020. It will be a narrow race in any case.

The alternatives

Altogether: Looking at 2020, it appears obvious that President &:Chairman Xi Jinping and the other political top leaders around him actually cannot “afford” a clear weakening of GDP growth. Such a negative development can either be counteracted  by further fiscal or monetary stimuli and/or by “window dressing” of GDP statistics (as critics interpreted surprising upward-revisions of GDP last fall).

It is hard to imagine that China’s political top leaders (in the Standing Committee) will remain passive without influencing GDP in a more positive direction. In my view, trying to remain relatively close to the official growth target will have political priority. But I do not want to give a GDP-growth number for 2020 at this very moment.

Conclusion

Clearly missing the annual growth target and/or the goal of doubling GDP would be negative or even embarrassing for China’s political leaders – unless the coronavirus really would make the situation much more critical. Consequently, keeping GDP growth for 2020 as close as possible to the “around 6-procent target” seems to be the guiding strategy.

Hubert Fromlet
Affiliate Professor at the School of Business and Economics, Linnaeus University
Editorial board

 

Back to Start Page

Laureate Esther Duflo and colleagues – admirable award courage in Stockholm

October 18, 2019

Pristagare Esther Duflo (och kolleger) – hurra för Nobelpriskommittén!

——————————————————————————————–

Summary in English

October 14 in 2019 turned out to be a great day also in my own professional life. I had no particular achievement myself but I could see something come true that I have been pleading for repeatedly for quite some time – the Nobel Prize in economic sciences with development economics as the awarded research area and Esther Duflo as a female winner together with Abhijit Banerjee. Concerning a third person I had in recent years changed my mind a couple of times forward and backward between Partha Dasgupta, William Easterley and Michael Kremer. Kremer made it finally – a good choice as well.

In recent years, I have pointed several times at my view that the evaluation time for the winning research area not in each and every case necessarily has to be 20-30 years – and certainly not when it comes to developing countries (poverty) and the scientific field experiments there.

———————————————————————————————

Own contributions / bidrag på svenska och engelska

https://lnu.se/en/meet-linnaeus-university/current/news/2019/who-will-be-awarded-the-nobel-prize-in-economics-2018/

https://blogg.lnu.se/fromlet-bbsresearch/files/2019/10/Nobel_Prizw_2019.pdf

https://johanschuck.se/hubert-fromlet-dags-for-en-ny-kvinnlig-ekonomipristagare/

https://lnu.se/mot-linneuniversitetet/aktuellt/nyheter/2019/hubert-fromlet-det-ar-hog-tid-att-hitta-kvinnliga-ekonomipristagare/

https://www.di.se/debatt/debatt-kvinnorna-som-borde-fa-ekonomipriset/

——————————————————————————————–

När jag igår fick höra resultatet från omröstningen till ekonomipriset 2019 blev jag mycket glad. Dels för att forskningsområdet “utvecklingsekonomi” belönades, dels för att Esther Duflo blev en av pristagarna (utan att göra avkall på de två manliga pristagarnas meriter). Det hade dock tagit så mycket som tio år sedan den första kvinnliga pristagaren hade belönats (Elinor Ostrom).

Jag hade också föreslagit i några av ovanstående länkar att – om det ej skulle uppstå kvalitativa risker – att (något) förkorta den traditionella, 20-30 år långa utvärderingsperioden för att kunna utvidga listan på kvinnliga priskandidater.

Så klart att jag kände mig nöjd efter tillkännagivandet. En del traditionellt skolade och sinnade kolleger framförde en hel del tvivel. Några sade också till mig rakt på sak att fältexperiment inte duger för att komma fram till generella eller makroorienterade slutsatser.

Visst, i vissa situationer kan det vara så. Har man dock sysslat lite närmare med fattiga utvecklingsländer brukar man märka rätt snabbt att effektiviteten och resultaten av speciella reformer och satsningar endast kan mätas med hjälp av fältorienterade mikroexperiment, speciellt eftersom makroekonomiskt statistikstöd av olika skäl knappt förekommer. Men neutralt vunna lokala eller regionala undersökningsresultat kan också göra mycket nytta och leda till bredare geografisk tillämpning.

Bra med Banerjees och Duflos forskning är inte minst att de kan åstadkomma praktisk koppling med sina studier och exempelvis även inkludera något så viktigt som psykologiska aktioner och reaktioner. Deras forskning är neutral och kan ej påverkas eller manipuleras av inhemska institutioner. Såväl berörda (fattiga) människor och inhemska institutioner kan dra direkt nytta av MIT-ekonomernas forskning som utländska biståndsgivare och företag. En helt ny forskargeneration kan äntligen mer konkret bidra till en bättre och rättvisare värld.

Min hyllning till Banerjee och Duflo ska dock inte förringa Michael Kremers mycket seriösa vetenskapliga insatser för fattiga länder, speciellt eftersom han sysslar så mycket med hälsoekonomi – ett viktigt forskningsområde med Amy Finkelstein, Jonathan Gruber och Kevin Murphy som potentiella pristagare längre fram. ”Health economics” förtjänar ännu mer uppmärksamhet framöver, både i utvecklade och mindre utvecklade länder.

Hubert Fromlet
Affiliate Professor at the School of Business and Economics, Linnaeus University
Editorial board

 

Back to Start Page

The size of currency reserves in emerging countries – a reliable indicator?

August 6, 2019

Är valutareserven en pålitlig indikator för ekonomisk stabilitet på tillväxtmarknader?

Sammanfattning på svenska / Summary in Swedish

¤  Valutareservens storlek framstår inte nödvändigtvis som en pålitlig ekonomisk bedömnings- eller stabilitetsfaktor på en s k tillväxtmarknad (emerging market). Men det är givetvis bättre att valutareseven till exempel täcker tio månaders import än bara två månaders import. Emerging markets behöver normalt längre importtäckning genom valutareserven än etablerade OECD/EU-länder.

¤  En viktig indikation är också i vilken utsträckning valutareserven kan täcka eventuella bytesbalansunderskott och åtaganden från utlandsskulder. Graden av finansmarknadernas avreglering för gränsöverskridande kapitalrörelser kan dock utgöra ett viktigare analysinslag. China till exempel är i detta avseende fortfarande starkt reglerat. Vidare ger den tidsmässiga fördelningen av utlandsupplåningen (korta mot längre krediter) viktig information om behovet av utlandsvaluta inom överskådlig tid.

¤  Ibland kan också en välfylld valutareserv snabbt leda till valutabrist och en ohållbar situation. Så skedde exempelvis i Mexiko 1994, i Thailand och Malaysia 1997 samt i Lettland år 2008.

———————————————

We still can note every month quite a number of comments on changes of the size of Chinese currency reserves (see my previous blog on chinaresearch.se) – also when economically irrelevant changes happen by just a few billion dollars. Of course, the size of currency reserves of a country deserves analytical attention (but usually not so much in OECD/EU countries).

Why is that need? There may be quite a number of reasons. Let me in this context sum up five of the most important ones.

Motives for a reasonable size of currency reserves

¤ Currency reserves must cover (normal and necessary) imports by emerging markets for quite some time. However, the definition of “quite some time” may vary. Of course, I like ten months import coverage better than only two months coverage.

¤ Currency reserves are also an important indicator for the ability to serve foreign debt commitments. Necessary reserve volumes for this purpose depend to a high extent on the size of the foreign debt. Usually, I would like to see that commitments from foreign debt and the current account are covered at least a couple of quarters ahead. But such a time horizon cannot function as reliable guidance either. Therefore, foreign-debt structure (short term vs long term) and bond rate differentials vis-à-vis USD bonds may give other and better indications than combined numerical warning signals for foreign debt and the current account balance.

¤ Currency reserves can be used to intervene on forex markets – usually not officially announced or confirmed – when the own currency is considered as being too strong or sometimes even too weak by domestic decision-makers, usually coming from the political sphere.

¤ The important development of an emerging country’s current account is also linked to the size of the currency reserves. However, deficits in the current account can only be financed in four ways,

  • by receiving foreign direct investments (FDI) -> usually the best way,
  • by borrowing money abroad -> with obvious limitations,
  • by selling treasury bills, bonds and stocks to other countries -> risky,
  • by reducing the currency reserves -> a very limited possibility.

¤ A relatively high level of currency reserves may also serve as a psychological indicator for economic and financial strength. This kind of function is certainly much more important in emerging countries than in advanced and at the same time well-working economies.

What is sufficient?

Unfortunately, there are no clear thumb rules about necessary currency volumes that may be high enough to have sufficient protection against a potential future economic and/or financial crisis. The mood of global financial markets may differ from time to time, and so may the quality of the government in the affected emerging market. Variations may also show up when it comes to contagion risks to other countries, to the GDP-growth situation in the global economy or to an emerging country’s ongoing deregulation process of the capital account.

Conclusion:
Altogether we should keep in mind that no safe prediction can be made about the sufficiently secure size of currency reserves in emerging markets. Mexico in 1994, Thailand and Malaysia in 1997and also Latvia in 2008 seemed to be on the safe side with the size of their pre-crisis levels of the currency reserves. However, developments became suddenly very stormy – and they derailed then very rapidly.

Hubert Fromlet
Affiliate Professor at the School of Business and Economics, Linnaeus University
Editorial board

 

Back to Start Page